Article

Reputational Incentives-How Improving Transparency Can Drive Hospital Competition

Register or Login to View PDF Permissions
Permissions× For commercial reprint enquiries please contact Springer Healthcare: ReprintsWarehouse@springernature.com.

For permissions and non-commercial reprint enquiries, please visit Copyright.com to start a request.

For author reprints, please email rob.barclay@radcliffe-group.com.
Average (ratings)
No ratings
Your rating

Disclosure:Nothing in this article is to be construed as the Department of Veterans Affairs' policy or procedure

Copyright Statement:

The copyright in this work belongs to Radcliffe Medical Media. Only articles clearly marked with the CC BY-NC logo are published with the Creative Commons by Attribution Licence. The CC BY-NC option was not available for Radcliffe journals before 1 January 2019. Articles marked ‘Open Access’ but not marked ‘CC BY-NC’ are made freely accessible at the time of publication but are subject to standard copyright law regarding reproduction and distribution. Permission is required for reuse of this content.

In 1209, when his soldiers were unable to distinguish the pious from the heretics, Arnaud Amalric ordered his men to “[k]ill them all [for] God will recognize his own!”1 To many individuals living in the 21st century, Amalric’s indiscriminate use of blunt force to massacre 20,000 Cathari may seem like ancient history. However, in the world of healthcare Amalric’s words seem to have become the unofficial mantra of reformers. The US spends $2 trillion a year on healthcare, or $10,000 per capita, while 47 million Americans cannot afford healthcare insurance coverage.2 Even before the current economic slump, the US could not afford its healthcare system. So, if the US is to remain competitive in a global economy, healthcare reform is no longer an issue; reform is coming and only the details remain to be resolved.

Unquestionably in the crosshairs of reformers is America’s over-consumption of healthcare services. According to 2006 World Health Organization (WHO) figures, the US spends more than twice as much per capita on healthcare as the UK or Japan.3 In particular, coronary interventions (coronary artery bypass grafting [CABG] or percutaneous coronary intervention [PCI]) are performed many times more frequently in the US than in Europe.4 The WHO’s data, which are corroborated by other reputable sources,5 suggest to healthcare reformers that coronary intervention is being over-prescribed in the US. However, lacking clinical acumen, reformers are hard-pressed to identify which patients could be managed medically and which require more invasive intervention.

Enter provider-specific report cards, a methodology ostensibly designed to improve patients’ autonomy by increasing market transparency.6 Recently, the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) launched its own report card on its Hospital Compare website.7 Already receiving 2.5 million hits per month, Hospital Compare ranks private hospitals according to performance measures, reimbursement, and risk-adjusted mortality.8 On the other hand, the realpolitik of provider-specific report cards (including Hospital Compare) is to enlist the aid of market forces9 to ration healthcare.10 More specifically, report cards use proxies (e.g. surgical-site infection [SSI] rate) to measure ‘quality,’ and an adverse report card can ruin a hospital’s reputation. To reformers, fewer hospitals means fewer services will be provided. However, the rather blunt nature of these quality proxies ensures that any reward or punishment a hospital receives based on its report card performance will be granted more or less indiscriminately.

So, from the perspective of hospitals, report-card-driven healthcare reform is likely to be perceived as a ‘kill all of the hospitals for the market will know which hospitals provide quality care’ downsizing program. Accordingly, after reviewing the evidence for a surplus of hospitals, this article discusses how provider-specific reports can create reputational incentives capable of reducing the number of hospitals providing coronary intervention.

Closing Hospitals

Surplus Capacity. Overall, the hospital bed capacity in the US is 3.0 per 1,000 population.11 This figure, however, varies from state to state and does not correlate with a state’s population density. Thus, several low-population-density states (North and South Dakota, Mississippi, Montana, Nebraska, and West Virginia) and high-population-density states (New York, Illinois, and Florida) have hospital bed capacity rates that exceed the 3.0 per 1,000 population mark.

To a degree, the disproportionately high hospital bed capacity rate found in many low-population-density states is deceptive. Hays, Kansas (population of 130,000) is the home of a 158-bed medical center that provides invasive cardiac services.12 If only the community of Hays is considered, Hays probably has a surplus of hospital beds. However, when it is realized that the nearest competing medical center that provides invasive cardiac services is 150 miles away in Wichita, Kansas, it could be argued that western Kansas has a shortage of hospital beds for providing cardiac services.

Yet does Philadelphia really need five hospitals that offer cardiac transplantation,13 and does Chicago really need 41 hospitals that provide cardiac surgery?14 To healthcare reformers many high-population-density regions have a surplus of hospital beds. For example, the Berger Commission recommended that New York State (NYS) eliminate 4,200 hospital beds (7% of the market) by closing nine hospitals.15 Similarly, a New Jersey commission concluded that the Hackensack market had an “oversupply of beds” that resulted in “serious financial distress” for the state.16

Surplus bed capacity concerns healthcare payors because it has been correlated with the over-utilization of healthcare services.17 In fields as diverse as pediatrics,18 surgery,19 and critical care medicine,20 markets with surplus bed capacity have physicians hospitalizing patients more frequently. Consequently, markets with surplus hospital bed capacity also tend to be the markets with highest per capita healthcare spending.21 This is not to say that high per capita healthcare spending is fundamentally bad. If such markets could show that excessive healthcare spending resulted in better outcomes, reformers would be silenced because such information would support the conclusion that in healthcare ‘you get what you pay for.’ Unfortunately for providers, the literature of the last 30 years has failed to demonstrate that regions with higher per capita spending have better clinical outcomes than the regions with low per capita spending.22 Even when utilization data are examined at the level of individual hospitals, it is not possible to demonstrate a positive correlation between healthcare spending and clinical outcomes.23

Collectively, these observations suggest to healthcare reformers that substantial reductions in healthcare spending can be achieved—without sacrificing quality—by reducing the number of hospitals (beds). To illustrate this, consider the potential savings that could be achieved if the US were able to reduce its hospital bed capacity by 5% (or 2% less than the downsizing figure recommended by the Berger Commission). With 31% of healthcare spending going to hospitals,24 such a reduction in hospital capacity could save $40 billion. Moreover, while the data are not conclusive, the mere act of closing a hospital can have a salutary effect on healthcare. When an urban hospital closes, competing hospitals within a five-mile radius of the closing hospital begin to operate more efficiently such that their unit-adjusted cost per admission actually falls by 2–4%.

Thus, it should come as no surprise that the government has already created incentives to downsize the hospital market. Some of these incentives include:

  • declining to pay for certain complications (thereby removing $4.8 billion/year from the hospital market);25
  • changing reimbursement rules to influence hospitals that provide “post-acute care services to alter their level of participation in Medicare;”26 and
  • cutting Medicaid reimbursement to safety net hospitals.27

However, now we reach the hard issue for healthcare reformers: which hospitals should be closed? In many communities the local hospital is the largest employer in the county,28 which makes it politically dangerous to directly attack and close a hospital by fiat.29 The Berger Commission’s use of a fiat decision-making process—regardless of how thoughtfully it was prepared—demonstrates just how much public backlash can be associated with fiat hospital closure. Politicians, who instinctively fear any public outcry as it may herald an unsuccessful re-election bid, cannot afford to leave their fingerprints on any legislation that would downsize the hospital market. Rather, a politically safer way to downsize the hospital market would be indirectly through the use of market forces. Leaving no fingerprints, the use of report cards to unleash market forces is favored by President Obama as a technique to reshape our healthcare market.30

Report Cards

History. In 2003, the Institute of Medicine (IOM) recommended that the US jettison its traditional administrative pricing of healthcare services.31 According to the IOM, a value-based purchasing (VBP) system not only would promote improvements in quality of care, but also would help control medical inflation. At its heart, VBP uses report cards to determine which providers should receive the carrot and those that will get the stick as their ‘reward.’ The carrot is the now familiar pay-for-performance bonuses that are given to providers who score well on their report cards. Conversely, providers who consistently fail to meet their performance measures are to be ‘removed’ from the market.32

Here we reach a paradoxical situation. A fundamental maxim of patient safety is that fear does not belong in the market,33 yet it is axiomatic that forcing providers out of the market is a formula for raising the market’s level of fear. To resolve this paradox it needs to be recognized that while the IOM has used patient safety as a pretext for healthcare reform, the cost-reduction subtext of the IOM’s publications makes it clear that patient safety reform is as much about saving money as it is about protecting patients.34 By using report-card-generated reputational incentives, market fears are assuaged because hospitals are given a choice: improve or exit the market.35

Shaping markets with reputational incentives is a great theory, but does it work? The definitive answer is not yet available because of the plurality of quality metrics and methodologies that are used to create report cards. The Joint Commission and several other patient safety organizations each has its own report cards, and none of these report cards has achieved universal acceptance.36 Moreover, the plurality of report cards is likely to confuse the public because hospitals are ranked differently by CMS’ Hospital Compare and US Newsweek’s Best Hospitals.37 As a plurality of methodologies makes comparison of report card rankings of hospitals difficult,38 “[s]erious issues have been raised about the accuracy, validity, meaningfulness, and interpretability” of hospital report cards.39

The Cardiac Surgery Model. Still, the market impact of reputational incentives can be demonstrated from studies of NYS’ cardiac services report card for hospitals.40 NYS’ cardiac services report card is a valuable model for studying the impact of report cards because:

  • the metrics and methodologies employed have been more or less constant for two decades;
  • it is the most studied report card model; and
  • this model has been adopted by a number of states, including California, Massachusetts, New Jersey and Pennsylvania.

In response to a freedom of information lawsuit, NYS reluctantly began publishing provider-specific data in 1989.41 At first, NYS’ cardiac services report card appeared to have little market impact. Peterson, for example, found that after the publication of an adverse report card, high-mortality hospitals experienced only a transient drop in the volume of cardiac surgical procedures performed.42 These early studies also tended to suggest that financial incentives trumped reputational incentives. Between 1994 and 2005, the number of NYS hospitals providing low-volume cardiac services grew by 10%,43 even though low-volume hospitals tend to have higher mortality rates.44

Yet by 2005 the studies coming out of NYS demonstrated solidly that reputational incentives do have market impact. Although a positive report card rarely translates into a hospital gaining market share,45 survey data indicate that an adverse report card can tarnish a hospital’s reputation.46 Once a hospital’s reputation for cardiac services has been tarnished, Medicare data have shown that the hospital becomes more risk-averse. In particular, a hospital with a tarnished image tends to:

  • ship more high-risk cardiac surgery cases to higher-volume institutions;47 and
  • offer fewer ancillary cardiac procedures:48 during a recent three-year period, a 33% reduction in the number of CABGs performed in NYS was better explained by the state’s report card publication than by cardiologists substituting PCIs for CABGs.

In addition, markets that use reputational incentives have significantly lower hospital mortality rates because only the best-risk patients are offered coronary intervention.49 Fearing even the smallest loss of reputation,50 hospitals encourage cardiac surgeons to ‘cherry-pick’ patients51 and encourage cardiologists to offer PCI to fewer patients with acute myocardial infarction. Not surprisingly, by 2005 NYS could boast that it had the lowest mortality rate for cardiac surgery in the country.52

Some might argue that NYS’ excellent cardiac surgery mortality rate was the end result of process improvement, but this seems unlikely. Longitudinally collected data suggest that the complexity of CABGs performed in NYS is decreasing. However, if process improvement were really the force driving down mortality, it would be expected that the improved hospitals should be better able to handle the complex cases—something that has not been observed. Moreover, little money is available for process improvement. With one-third of hospitals operating with a negative profit margin53 and CMS continuing to reduce the profitability of providing cardiac services,54 discretionary funds are in short supply.

When these economic realities are coupled with the collapse of the bond market,55 it is unlikely that the financial health of hospitals will improve any time soon.56 This means that a hospital that receives low marks on a report card is unlikely to have the necessary cash to fund a quality improvement program to restore its image. So, in the future when a hospital’s reputation is sullied by a bad report card, its options are likely to be limited to shuttering or merging the program.57 Either way, the reputational incentives associated with the publication of provider-specific report cards encourages the downsizing of cardiac services markets.

Who Benefits? So, who benefits when NYS publishes its annual cardiac surgery report cards? An obvious beneficiary is any hospital located in a state that does not publish report cards. The Cleveland Clinic, for example, experienced a 31% increase in its volume of (high-risk) CABG procedures after NYS began publishing report cards.58 Yet, as we go forward, hospitals in states that do not utilize reputational incentives will not be as fortunate.

As a national report card, Hospital Compare will allow patients located on either side of a state line to discover a hospital’s quality metrics. So, even if a hospital is located in a state that does not publish provider-specific report cards, Hospital Compare provides an incentive for all hospitals to think twice about to whom it offers coronary intervention. Similarly, hospitals that are dependent on performing a certain volume of cardiac services to stay afloat will increasingly find this strategy to be perilous. Any hospital that is strategically dependent on performing a certain volume of coronary interventions could have their finances upset by an adverse report card.

This, of course, is exactly what federal government wants. Every time a provider declines to offer a patient either PCI or CABG, the government saves money. Viewed in this light, while report cards may improve market transparency, it is also clear that report cards function as a device to ration healthcare. For politicians and reformers, the beauty of unleashing market forces with Hospital Compare is that the cause and effect of report-card- induced market downsizing is blurred. As market forces do not leave the cachet of any governmental agency, it will be the hospitals and physicians who have declined to offer patients for coronary intervention that will be exposed to the public’s ire. Meanwhile, the government will happily take full credit for creating Hospital Compare to expose low-quality providers.

Implications

Now imagine your 65-year-old father has two-vessel coronary disease. While experts in the field debate the optimal treatment for this condition,59 your father’s cardiologist recommends that he receive a CABG, which can be performed at either a traditional hospital or a heart hospital. When your father consults Hospital Compare, he discovers, with three exceptions, that the traditional and heart hospitals have almost identical statistics. The three exceptions are:

  • last year the heart hospital performed twice as many CABGs as the traditional hospital;
  • the SSI rate at the heart hospital is 3% greater than at the traditional hospital; and
  • the cost of the CABG is substantially cheaper at the heart hospital.

Indeed, your father discovers that on the Hospital Compare website, heart hospitals are usually the least expensive provider of cardiac services in their local market. Figuring that you get what you pay for, your father selects the traditional hospital, hoping to avoid an SSI. However, to your father’s chagrin, the traditional hospital declines to offer him an operation. He later undergoes a CABG without complication at the heart hospital.

Once it is accepted that report cards are a ‘kill-them-all’ scheme for rationing healthcare, all of the actors in the above hypothetical situation behave logically. As most patients are not trained in statistics, they do not realize that a 3% difference in the incidence of SSIs at two hospitals is unlikely to be statistically significant. The Hospital Compare website, which has several footnotes for qualifying data, makes no attempt to provide patients with information on statistical inferences. Consequently, there is no way for your father to learn from Hospital Compare that the differences in SSI rate between the traditional and heart hospital are likely to be due to chance alone. Nor does Hospital Compare disclose the fact that the risk of an SSI has as much to do with a patient’s comorbidities as it does with the measured quality metrics of antibiotic administration, maintenance of normothermia during the peri-operative period, and post-operative glucose control.60

Indeed, it is precisely because of your father’s chronic renal insufficiency (CRI) that the traditional hospital turned him down for revascularization. Operating at a much lower case volume, the traditional hospital can ill afford bad outcomes, including an SSI, which occurs more frequently in patients with CRI. Wishing to avoid bad publicity, the traditional hospital has placed pressure on its single cardiac surgeon not to offer a CABG to any patient with CRI.

While this policy may be successful in maintaining the hospital’s image for cardiac services in the short term, over the long term this policy is likely to have a deleterious impact. As the hospital becomes increasingly more risk-averse, its volume of cardiac services continues to contract. In a hospital dependent on performing a certain volume of CABG cases to cross-subsidize other services, the traditional hospital will become less capable of carrying out its mission of providing all services to all patients. There is also a catch-22: by offering fewer patients coronary intervention, the hospital becomes even less capable of handling the impact of an adverse outcome. This fact then sets off another round of risk avoidance behavior, resulting in further volume contraction.

In contrast, operating at a higher case load, the heart hospital in the hypothetical situation is in a better position to handle the risks associated with your father’s CRI. That is, in a reportcard- monitored market the higher-volume heart hospitals can profit because they can better handle the risks of providing coronary intervention. Still, for heart hospitals, the reputational incentives highlighted in this hypothetical situation have two implications.

First, in a market where patients are increasingly engaged in comparison shopping, the delivery of quality coronary intervention at a good price is unlikely to maintain market share. As time goes on, traditional hospitals will emulate heart hospital behavior. Second, heart hospitals should lead the way in educating patients on the pitfalls of report card interpretation to engender patient goodwill—a ‘quality metric’ that is not measured on the Hospital Compare website.

Consider your father. It is a stress-riser for any patient to undergo a CABG at their second-choice hospital. So, using Hospital Compare to comparison-shop for a surgical procedure, it is not unreasonable to believe your father was made more anxious. While it is hard to place a dollar value on such anxiety, it is nonetheless a real hardship for the patient. So, it seems likely that any hospital that takes the time to educate patients on the pitfalls of report card interpretation will only profit from the cultivation of goodwill.

Conclusion

Report cards may be a blunt instrument for downsizing the hospital market, but few healthcare economists doubt the effectiveness of reputational incentives. Nor is the government likely to retreat from publishing provider-specific data. Next year the government is planning to spend $1.1 billion on comparative healthcare effectiveness research.61 Armed with these data, the government will determine which coronary interventions are ‘medically indicated.’

Once that happens, watch for a new quality metric, ‘inappropriate treatment,’ to be posted on Hospital Compare. Can you imagine what patients will think when they read that 10% of the CABGs performed at the local hospital were deemed ‘inappropriate treatment’? Sounds far-fetched? Perhaps. Yet the important point here is that hospitals with strategic plans to provide coronary interventions should amend those plans to include not only the resources to provide high-quality care, but also to include funding for public education on report card interpretation. 

The author wishes to thank Ms Rosemarie A Adkins, librarian for the Eastern Kansas VA Healthcare System, for her assistance in gathering reference material.

References

  1. Massacare of the Pure, Time, April 18, 1961. Available at: www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,897752-1,00.html (accessed May 15, 2009).
  2. Montgomery JW, U.S. health care reform: does corporate America get it?, Blue Cross Blue Shield of Florida, July 26, 2008. Available at: www.nmanet.org/images/uploads/John_Montgomery_2008_Mazi que_Pres.pdf (accessed May 16, 2009).
  3. Poole-Wilson PA, Cardiovascular health in Europe: A global problem, J Am Coll Cardiol, 2007;49:117–19.
  4. McLean TR, In New York State, do more percutaneous coronary interventions mean fewer or more complex referral to cardiac surgeons?, Am Heart Hosp J, 2008;6:30–36.
  5. OECD, OECD Health Data 2008 – Frequently Requested Data, 2008. Available at: www.oecd.org/document/16/0,3343,en_2649 _34631_2085200_1_1_1_1,00.html (accessed September 14, 2008).
  6. McLean TR, Informed consent and clinician accountability: The ethics of report cards on surgeon performance, JAMA, 2009; 301(2):224–5.
  7. www.hospitalcompare.hhs.gov
  8. Graham J, Government posts hospital death rates, Chi Trib, 2008 Aug 20 (Epub ahead of print).
  9. McLean TR, Application of administrative law to health care reform: the real politik of crossing the quality chasm, J Law Health, 2001;16(1):65–76.
  10. McLean TR, Medical rationing: the implicit result of Leadership by Example, J Health Law, 2003;36(2):325–63.
  11. Social Rank, Medical infrastructure – hospital closures and access to health care. Available at: social.jrank.org/pages/1202/Medical- Infrastructure-Hospital-Closures-Access-Health-Care.html (accessed September 14, 2008).
  12. Hays Medical Center. Available at: portal.haysmed.com/portal/ page?_pageid=43,1&_dad=portal&_schema=PORTAL (accessed May 27, 2009).
  13. Graham J, Too many heart centers, not enough transplants: Fewer severely ill patients in Chicago are receiving the lifesaving treatment, Newstex, April 13, 2008. Available at: www.bcbs.com/ news/national/too-many-heart-centers-not-enough-transplantsfewer- severely-ill-patients-in-chicago-are-receiving-the-lifesavingtreatment. html (accessed September 14, 2008).
  14. Hospital Directory Search, US News and World Reports, September 14, 2008. Available at: health.usnews.com/directories/hospitaldirectory/ index_html/state+IL/msa+1600/type+gen/name+/zip+ /sort+dist/page_number+1/page_size+10/+undefined/service+O HSG (accessed September 14, 2008).
  15. Solomont EB, Hospital bed cuts to fall short of Berger recommendations, The Sun, July 7, 2008. Available at: www.nysun.com/health-fitness/hospital-bed-cuts-to-fall-short-ofberger/ 81316/ (accessed September 14, 2008).
  16. Groves B, More hospital closures to come, The Record, January 25, 2008. Available at: www.northjersey.com/health/Panel_sees_ surplus_of_hospitals.html (accessed September 14, 08).
  17. Karash JA, Tough words on what U.S. spends on health care, KC Star, February 8, 2008.
  18. Guagliardo MF, Huang ZJ, LaFleur B, et al., Does pediatric bed supply influence infant hospitalization rate?, Acad Health Serv Res Health Policy, 2000. Available at: gateway.nlm.nih.gov/Meeting Abstracts/ma?f=102272403.html (accessed September 14, 2008).
  19. Tanner M, The grass is not always greener, Cato Institute, March 18, 2008. Available at: www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-613.pdf (accessed September 14, 2008).
  20. Hospital Specific Data FAQ, Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care. Available at: www.dartmouthatlas.org/faq/hospital.shtm (accessed September 14, 2008).
  21. Berwick, DM, Invasive procedures: Less Is More… and Better, Newsweek, 2007. Available at: www.msnbc.msn.com/id/15176095/ site/newsweek/print/1/displaymode/1098 (accessed September 14, 2008).
  22. Fisher ES, JE Wenberg, Stukal TA, et al., The implications of regional variations in Medicare spending, Ann Int Med, 2003;138: 273–87.
  23. Yasaitis L, Fisher ES, Skinner JS, et al., Hospital quality and intensity of spending: is there an association?, Health Affairs, 2009;28(4): w566–w572.
  24. National Conference of State Legislatures: Hospitals and State legislatures, August 2008. Available at: www.ncsl.org/programs/ health/hospitals.htm (accessed August 23, 2008).
  25. CMS issues rule aimed at reducing “Never Events,” Medical Economics, August 8, 2008. Available at: medicaleconomics. modernmedicine.com/memag/Doctors%27+Legal+Forum/CMSIssues- Rule-Aimed-At-Reducing-Never-Events/ArticleStandard/ Article/detail/534850?contextCategoryId=44341 (accessed August 23, 2008).
  26. Kulesher RW, Wilder MG, The impact of PPS on hospitalsponsored post-acute services, a case study of Delaware Medicare providers, J Healthc Manag, Jan–Feb 2008. Available at: www.entrepreneur.com/tradejournals/article/174372612.html (accessed September 14, 2008).
  27. Massive Medicaid cuts will impact all Floridians, safety net hospital leaders warn, Medical News Today, April 11, 2008. Available at: www.medicalnewstoday.com/articles/103600.php (accessed September 14, 2008).
  28. Hammer PJ, Sage WM, Antitrust, health care quality, and the courts, Columbia Law Review, 2002;102:545–649.
  29. Friedman A, Muhlenberg hospital closure will be address at Plainfield hearing, NJ.com, May 6, 2008. Available at: www.nj.com/ news/index.ssf/2008/05/muhlenberg_hospital_closure_wi.html (accessed September 14, 2008).
  30. Rosenthal MB, What works in market-oriented health policy?, N Engl J Med, 2009;360(21):2157–60.
  31. Institute of Medicine, Leadership by Example: Coordinating Government Roles in Improving Health Care Quality, Washington, DC: NAS Press, 2002.
  32. Institute of Medicine, Rewarding Provider Performance: Aligning Incentives in Medicare, Washington, DC: NAS Press, 2006.
  33. Institute of Medicine, To Err is Human: Building a Better Healthcare System, Washington, DC: NAS Press, 1999.
  34. McLean TR, The implications of patient safety research and risk managed care, Southern Illinois University Law, 2002;26:227–75.
  35. McLean TR, Will reputational incentives stimulate a reversal of the physician brain drain?, J Health Serv Res Policy, 2008;13:50–52.
  36. Kallem C, Fenton SH, Needed: Data content standards, J AHIMA, 2007;78(1):60–61.
  37. Halasyamani LK, Davis MM, Conflicting measures of hospital quality: Ratings from “Hospital Compare” versus “Best Hospitals,” J Hosp Med, 2007;2(3):128–34.
  38. Shahian DM, Silverstein T, Lovett AF, et al., Comparison of clinical and administrative data sources for hospital coronary artery bypass graft surgery report cards, Circulation, 2007;115:1518–27.
  39. Epstein AJ, Do cardiac surgery report cards reduce mortality?, Med Care Res Rev, 2006;63(4):403–26.
  40. Department of Public Health, Cardiovascular Disease Data and Statistics. Available at: www.health.state.ny.us/statistics/diseases/ cardiovascular/ (accessed September, 2008).
  41. Nuffield Trust and RAND, Dying to know: public release of information about quality of health care, 2005. Available at: www.rand.org/pubs/monograph_reports/2005/MR1255.pdf (accessed August 23, 2008).
  42. Peterson ED, DeLong ER, Jollis JG, et al., The effects of New York’s bypass surgery provider profiling on access to care and patient outcomes in the elderly, J Am Coll Cardiol, 1998;32(4):993–9.
  43. Wilson CT, Fisher ES, Welch HG, et al., U.S. trends in CABG hospital volume: The effect of adding cardiac surgery programs, Health Affairs, 2007;26(1):162–8.
  44. Birkmeyer JD, Siewers AE, Finlayson EV, et al., Hospital volume and surgical mortality in the United States, N Engl J Med, 2002;346: 1128–37.
  45. Jha AK, Epstein AJ, The predictive accuracy of the New York State coronary artery bypass surgery report-card system, Health Aff, 2006; 25(3):844–55.
  46. Hibbard JH, Stockard J, Tusler M, Hospital performance reports: impact on quality, market share, and reputation, Health Aff, 2005;24(4);1150–60.
  47. Cutler DM, Huckman RS, Landrum MD, The role of information in medical markets: an analysis of publicly reported outcomes in cardiac surgery, American Economic Review, 2004;94(2):342–6.
  48. Dranove D, Kessler D, McClellan M, et al., Is more information better? The effects of report cards on health care providers, NBER Working Paper No. 8697, January 2002. Available at: papers.nber.org/papers/w8697 (accessed September 8, 2008).
  49. Hollenbeak CS, Gorton CP, Tobak YP, et al., Deductions in mortality associated with intensive public reporting of hospital outcomes, Am J Med Quality, 2008;23(4):279–86.
  50. Kahneman D, Tversky A, Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica, 1979;47:263–92.
  51. Albert M, Halevy N, Antman E, Preoperative evaluation for cardiac surgery. in: Cohl LH (ed.), Cardiac Surgery in the Adult, New York: McGraw-Hill, 2008.
  52. Santora M, Cardiologists say rankings sway choices on surgery, NY Times, January 11, 2005 (internet edition).
  53. Japen B, U. of C. medical practices drawing critical eye, Chi Trib, Sept 8, 2008 (internet edition).
  54. Hayes KJ, Pettengill J, Stensland J, Getting the price right: Medicare payment rates for cardiovascular services, Health Affairs, 2007;26:124–36.
  55. Fitch, For-profit U.S. hospital industry weakened in 4th quarter, Reuters, March 13, 2008. Available at: www.reuters.com/article/ pressRelease/idUS147091+13-Mar-2008+BW20080313 (accessed September 3, 2008).
  56. Evans M, Healthcare is getting worse, Modern Health Care, June 30, 2008. Available at: modernhealthcare.com/apps/pbcs.dll/ article?AID=/20080630/SUB/594767074&nocache=1&nocache=1 (accessed September 6, 2008).
  57. Colliver V, St. Luke’s Hospital owner puts off plan to cut service, SFGate.com, October 27, 2007. Available at: www.sfgate.com/cgibin/ article.cgi?f=/c/a/2007/10/26/BA89T0ERM.DTL&type=prin table (accessed September 6, 2008).
  58. Omoigui NA, Miller DP, Brown KJ, et al., Outmigration for coronary bypass surgery in an era of public dissemination of clinical outcomes, Circulation, 1996;93:27–33.
  59. Smith P, Treatment selection for coronary artery disease: Collision of a belief system with evidence, Ann Thor Surg, 2009;87(5):1328–30.
  60. American College of Surgeons, Surgical Education and Self- Assessment Program, Chicago, IL, 2007.
  61. The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009; Pub.L. 111-5.